Page 87 - India Insurance Report 2023- BIMTECH
P. 87

India Insurance Report - Series II                                                          75


        2. Sovereign Risk Financing

            Given the uncertainty of the occurrence of a shock, governments normally smooth expenditure on
        disaster relief from current income. Compared to households, which risk being wiped out by a disaster,
        governments usually only have to deal with damage to a fraction of the economy. A localized, provincial
        shock is likely to have little impact on the revenue of the national government compared to that of the
        provincial government. Although revenue from taxation may not guarantee ex-post relief, even if it does,
        it may reward bad behaviour by governments. If a future bailout through additional taxation is seen as
        cost-neutral, governments are more willing to forego prevention and spend only when a disaster occurs.
        The level of ex-ante spending on loss prevention or risk financing is viewed as costly, and therefore, they
        tend to spend less on prevention relative to relief.

            Further, the increasing frequency and severity of natural hazards and extreme weather events have
        raised the economic costs  associated with these events. Government finances are vulnerable on two
        fronts. First, economic activity may contract in the short term, lowering revenue collection. Second,
        post-disaster relief and reconstruction efforts may increase government expenditure and crowd out other
        priority spending, with potentially long-lasting effects on human capital accumulation and an economy’s
        potential growth rate.
            Both physical and transition risks impair asset values and the credit quality of loans and investments
        from  banks,  financial  institutions,  insurers,  and  capital  markets.  In  the  absence  of  appropriate
        countercyclical financing mechanisms, like income-smoothing social safety nets and public insurance
        schemes, this can create sizeable implicit contingent liabilities for governments.

            Yet, governments have been slow to integrate climate risk and its threat to financial systems into
        their decision-making and strategies. Governments looking to maximize their revenue while simultaneously
        focusing on social welfare can make people better off by spending more on disaster mitigation and by
        putting in place ex-ante risk financing mechanisms to lessen the impact of potential shocks.



        3. Additional Taxation


            Since disaster relief is also about raising additional revenues to finance such efforts, governments
        can consider additional taxation. Developed countries provide some good examples. The United States
        tax code offers both longstanding tax breaks and temporary tax relief for specific disasters. After the
        2011 earthquake, Japan introduced a 2.1% temporary surtax on income for 25 years (2013–2037) to
        finance reconstruction. Likewise, the Australian government responded to the 2011 Queensland floods
        by levying a one-year, one-off national flood reconstruction income tax to rebuild infrastructure.

            A few countries are also exploring the potential of taxes to finance disaster relief. Ecuador paid for
        a 2016 earthquake by increasing the value-added tax rate from 12% to 14% for one year and imposing
        one-off taxes of 0.9% on people with wealth over $1 million and 3% on business profits. India’s GST
        Council has been in discussion for tweaking the nationwide goods and services tax to mobilize revenue
        for post-disaster rebuilding, and in 2015, the state of Maharashtra temporarily raised taxes on tobacco
        and spirits by 5% to help farmers recover from drought.
   82   83   84   85   86   87   88   89   90   91   92