Page 202 - Environment: The Science Behind the Stories
P. 202

activities.  This is beginning to happen, but lobbying from   16
                        entrenched interests is keeping progress slow.                Emissions after first year of
                                                                               14     cap-and-trade program   Allowances allocated
                                                                                                              to recent years
                        We can harness market dynamics                         12
                        to promote sustainability                              10

                        With subsidies and green taxes, policymakers employ finan-
                        cial incentives in direct and selective ways. However, we may   SO 2  emissions (million tons)  8
                        also pursue policy goals by establishing financial incentives   6
                        and then letting marketplace dynamics run their course. One
                        example is ecolabeling (p. 173), the practice whereby sellers   4
                        who use sustainable practices in growing, harvesting, or manu-
                        facturing their products advertise this fact on their labels, hop-  2
                        ing to win approval from buyers. In many cases, ecolabeling
                        has grown from initial steps taken by government to require   0
                        the disclosure of information to consumers. Once established,   1990  1995  1996  1997  1998  1999  2000  2001  2002  2003  2004  2005  2006  2007  2008  2009  2010
                        ecolabeling can spread in a free market as more and more                       Year
                        businesses seek to win consumer confidence and to outcom-
                        pete less sustainably produced brands. Another example of   Figure 7.16 Permit trading has helped to reduce emissions
                        employing market dynamics for policy goals is permit trading.  of sulfur dioxide by 67% since 1990. As of 2010, emissions
                                                                             from U.S. sources participating in the program mandated by the
                                                                             1990 Clean Air Act amendments had dropped well below the
                        Permit trading can save money                        amount allocated in permits (black line). Data from U.S. Environmental
                                                                             Protection Agency.
                        and produce results

                        In  the  innovative  market-based  approach  known  as  permit   then, sulfur dioxide emissions from sources in the program
                        trading, the government creates a market in permits for an   have declined by 67% (Figure 7.16), sulfate deposition has
                        environmentally harmful activity, and companies, utilities, or   been reduced, and air quality and visibility have improved.
                        industries then buy, sell, or trade rights to conduct the  activity.   The 67% reduction in pollution was greater than the amount
                        To decrease emissions of air pollutants, a government might   actually required by the legislation, offering evidence that
                        grant emissions permits and set up an emissions  trading  system.   cap-and-trade systems can sometimes cut pollution more
                        In a cap-and-trade emissions trading system, the government   effectively than command-and-control regulation. Moreover,
                        first determines the overall amount of pollution it will accept   the cuts were attained at much less cost than was predicted
                        (i.e., it caps the total amount allowed) and then issues permits   and with no apparent effect on electricity supply or economic
                        to polluters that allow them each to emit a certain fraction of   growth. Savings from the permit trading system have been
                        that amount. Polluters may buy, sell, and trade these permits   estimated at billions of dollars per year, and the EPA calculates
                        with other polluters.                                that the program’s benefits outweigh its costs by about 40 to
                            Suppose, for example, you own an industrial plant with   1. Other similar programs have also shown success, including
                        permits to release 10 units of pollution, but you find that you   one in the Los Angeles basin to reduce smog (p. 473) and one
                        can make your plant more efficient and release only 5 units   among northeastern states aimed at nitrogen oxides.  CHAPTER 7 • Envi R onm E n TA l Poli C y :  mA king D EC i si ons  A n D   s olving P R obl E m s
                        instead. You then have a surplus of permits, which might be   Although cap-and-trade programs can reduce pollution,
                        very valuable to some other plant owner who is having trou-  they do allow hotspots of pollution to occur around plants that
                        ble reducing pollution or who wants to expand production. In   buy permits to pollute more. Moreover, large firms can hoard
                        such a case, you can sell your extra permits. Doing so gener-  permits, deterring smaller new firms from entering the market,
                        ates income for you and meets the needs of the other plant,   thereby suppressing competition. Nonetheless, permit trading
                        while the total amount of pollution does not rise. By provid-  shows promise for safeguarding environmental quality while
                        ing companies an economic incentive to find ways to reduce   granting industries the flexibility to lessen their impacts in
                        emissions, permit trading can reduce expenses for both indus-  ways that are economically palatable.
                        try and the public relative to a conventional regulatory system.  In recent years, emissions trading programs have begun
                            To lower emissions further, the government may reduce   to address the greenhouse gas emissions that drive global
                        the amount of overall emissions allowed year by year. Envi-  climate change. In the European Union Emission  Trading
                        ronmental organizations may buy up permits and “retire”   Scheme (p. 530), each participating nation allocates emis-
                        them, reducing the overall amount of pollution still more. To   sions permits to its industries according to their emissions
                        see an illustration of how a cap-and-trade system works, jump   at the start of the program.  The industries then can trade
                        ahead to Figure 18.31 (p. 531).                      permits freely, establishing a market whereby the price of
                            A cap-and-trade system has been in place in the United   a permit fluctuates according to supply and demand. In the
                        States, established by the 1990 amendments to the Clean Air   United States, the Chicago Climate Exchange pioneered
                        Act (p. 476) that mandated lower emissions of sulfur dioxide,   this approach, and carbon-trading programs are running
                        a major contributor to acid deposition (pp. 491–493). Since   in    California and among the northeastern states, although   201







           M07_WITH7428_05_SE_C07.indd   201                                                                                    12/12/14   2:57 PM
   197   198   199   200   201   202   203   204   205   206   207