Page 281 - Krugmans Economics for AP Text Book_Neat
P. 281

Rearranging Equation 24-2 to solve for $X, the amount you need today in order to re-
                                                                                         The present value of $1 realized one
             ceive $1 one year from now is:
                                                                                         year from now is equal to $1/(1 + r ):
                                                                                         the amount of money you must lend out
                  (24-3) Amount lent today in order to receive $1 one year from now =    today in order to have $1 in one year. It
                        $X = $1/(1 + r)                                                  is the value to you today of $1 realized
                                                                                         one year from now.            Section 5 The Financial Sector
               This means that you would be willing to accept today the amount $X defined by
             Equation 24-3 for every $1 to be paid to you one year from now. The reason is that if
             you were to lend out $X today, you would be assured of receiving $1 one year from now.
             Returning to our original question, this also means that if someone promises to pay
             you a sum of money one year in the future, you are willing to accept $X today in place
             of every $1 to be paid one year from now.
               Now let’s solve Equation 24-3 for the value of $X. To do this we simply need to use the
             actual value of r (a value determined by the financial markets). Let’s assume that the ac-
             tual value of r is 10%, which means that r = 0.10. In that case:

                  (24-4) Value of $X when r = 0.10: $X = $1/(1 + 0.10) = $1/1.10 = $0.91

             So you would be willing to accept $0.91 today in exchange for every $1 to be paid to
             you one year from now. Economists have a special name for $X—it’s called the present
             value of $1. Note that the present value of any given amount will change as the interest
             rate changes.
               To see that this technique works for evaluating future costs as
             well as evaluating future benefits, consider the following example.
             Suppose you enter into an agreement that obliges you to pay $1 one
             year from now—say, to pay off a car loan from your parents when
             you graduate in a year. How much money would you need today to
             ensure that you have $1 in a year? The answer is $X, the present
             value of $1, which in our example is $0.91. The reason $0.91 is the
             right answer is that if you lend it out for one year at an interest rate
             of 10%, you will receive $1 in return at the end. So if, for example,
             you must pay back $5,000 one year from now, then you need to de-
             posit $5,000 × 0.91 = $4,550 into a bank account today earning an  mptvimages.com
             interest rate of 10% in order to have $5,000 one year from now.
             (There is a slight discrepancy due to rounding.) In other words,
                                                                                         In the 1971 movie Willy Wonka and the
             today you need to have the present value of $5,000, which equals $4,550, in order to  Chocolate Factory, Veruca Salt appreci-
             be assured of paying off your debt in a year.                               ated the added value of having things in
               These examples show us that the present value concept provides a way to calculate  the present. She wanted a “golden-egg-
             the value today of $1 that is realized in a year—regardless of whether that $1 is realized  laying-goose NOW!”
             as a benefit (the bonus) or a cost (the car loan payback). To evaluate a project today
             that has benefits, costs, or both to be realized in a year, we just use the relevant interest
             rate to convert those future dollars into their present values. In that way we have “fac-
             tored out” the complication that time creates for decision making.
               Below we will use the present value concept to evaluate a project. But before we do
             that, it is worthwhile to note that the present value method can be used for projects in
             which the $1 is realized more than a year later—say, two, three, or even more years. Sup-
             pose you are considering a project that will pay you $1 two years from today. What is
             the value to you today of $1 received two years into the future? We can find the answer
             to that question by expanding our formula for present value.
               Let’s call $V the amount of money you need to lend today at an interest rate of r
             in order to have $1 in two years. So if you lend $V today, you will receive $V × (1 + r) in
             one year. And if you re-lend that sum for another year, you will receive $V × (1 + r) ×
                              2
             (1 + r) = $V × (1 + r) at the end of the second year. At the end of two years, $V will be
                            2
             worth $V × (1 + r) . In other words:
                  (24-5) Amount received in one year from lending $V = $V × (1 + r)

                                                                   module 24      The Time Value of Money       239
   276   277   278   279   280   281   282   283   284   285   286