Page 13 - QEB_2_2016_lowres
P. 13

There are very few numbers that can instil excitement and depression quite like Gross
              Domestic  Product  (GDP).  Government  policies  are  shaped,  budgets  are  set,  debt
              ceilings are determined and, at office watering holes, this mystical number is analysed
              by  economists  and  laymen  alike.  Our  very  sense  of  wellbeing  is  directly  influenced
              by  the  publication  of  the  number.  While  most  of  us  understand  GDP  as  a  measure
              of economic health, not many of us who use GDP have an appreciation of what the
              measure actually counts and what it omits in reflecting overall economic health.

              So, here is a piece of GDP trivia that I’m sure might have escaped you. In 2008, Bermuda
              eclipsed Luxembourg to record the second highest GDP per capita ($93 000). It was
              only  the  small,  oil-rich  state  of  Qatar  that  recoded  a  higher  GDP  per  head.  Today,
              Bermuda’s GDP per capita is 70% more than that of the United States. I don’t know
              about you, but all that comes to my mind when I think of Bermuda are bronze bodies
              meandering across the even bronzier beaches – certainly not the global model of
              industrialisation and productive economic growth.

              This begs, what I think, a set of rather important questions about GDP, such as: what
              does it measure, how is it measured, what can it be used for, and what does it say
              about our economic well-being?


              Origins of GDP
              The concept of GDP was first developed by William Petty to defend landlords against
              unfair and unsustainable taxation during the Dutch-English wars of the mid-1600s. His
              calculation entailed a very crude method to determine the total production of goods
              and services.

              It was not until 1933 that Kuznets, at the request of the US congress, produce a method              PROVINCIAL OUTLOOK      NATIONAL OUTLOOK      GLOBAL OUTLOOK      GAP HOUSING      INVESTOR NARRATIVE      SPOT THE OPPORTUNITY      PORTFOLIO INSIGHTS      KHULISA NEWSLETTER      ELECTRIC VEHICLES      ENERGY SECURITY      LOOKING AT GDP
              sufficiently sophisticated to calculate GDP in an industrial economy. The concept of
              GDP was further promoted by John Maynard Keynes, who is generally regarded as the
              father of macroeconomics.

              I am always taken aback by the fact that while concepts of trade, clear distinctions
              between labour and capital classes, factors of production and money are all hundreds
              if not thousands of years old, but the study of macroeconomics as we know it today is
              barely 70 years old. Perhaps it was because central to the study of macroeconomics
              is macro-indicators such as employment levels, inflation and, of course, GDP, none of
              which were available to the economist before the 20th century.

              Accurately  measuring  macro-indicators  such  as  GDP,  employment  and  inflation  as
              frequently as four times a year, is a mammoth task. The accuracy of the estimation is
              correlated to both cost and time. To improve the cost-benefit ratio of collecting and
              presenting macroeconomic statistics timeously, a very small part of the economy is
              surveyed and modelled. With any survey data, in inferring the characteristics of the
              population from a survey, we accept a combination of sampling, measurement,
              coverage and response errors.

              To increase confidence in GDP, we do measure GDP in three different ways, by:
              a)  aggregating all spend in the economy (expenditure approach),
              b)  adding all earnings in the economy (income approach), or
              c)  adding all value added (production approach), that is the price of outputs less the
                  price of intermediate inputs.






                                                             QUARTERLY ECONOMIC BULLETIN 2016         9
   8   9   10   11   12   13   14   15   16   17   18