Page 366 - Arabia the Gulf and the West
P. 366

The Masquerade                                         363



           as compensation the sum of 300 million francs over a period of seven years.
           CFP in its turn undertook to pay retrospective taxes to Algeria and to repatri­
           ate a substantial proportion of the profits it earned from sales of oil for
           investment in the development of Algeria’s oil reserves. The posted price of
           Algerian crude was fixed at $2.95 a barrel. The agreement between the two
           partners was to run for five years in the first instance, and to be renewed for a
           further five years by mutual agreement.
              Unless CFP was under pressure from the French government to give in to
           the Algerians it is not easy to see why it did so, especially over the question of
           proper compensation. ELF-ERAP certainly put up a better fight, for all that

           ERAP was a state enterprise. It was not until the end of 1971 that the company
           reached an understanding with SONATRACH. While it had originally
           sought to obtain the sum of 185 million francs as compensation for the
           nationalization of 51 per cent of its shareholding, it agreed in the end to forgo
           payment in return for the cancellation of the Algerian demand for retrospective
            taxes - which only went to show that the demand itself had no basis in legality.
            In an agreement signed on 15 December 1971 ELF-ERAP was guaranteed a
           yearly quota, at a posted price of $2.75 a barrel, of six million tons of crude oil,

           which was about one-third of what it might have expected to receive if it had
           not lost its majority shareholding. The agreement, like that with CFP, was to
            run for five years and to be renewed by mutual consent. What it all amounted
            to, in effect, was a decision by ELF-ERAP to write off its Algerian assets as
            not worth holding on to.


            The obvious moral to be drawn from the experience of the French oil com­
            panies in Algeria was that it was utterly pointless, from the point of view of an
            oil-consuming country, to try to ensure security of oil supplies by direct
            arrangements with the government of an oil-producing state. The arrangement

            had failed primarily because of the bad faith of the Algerian government,
            which had broken every agreement it had freely entered into, whether with the
            French government or with the French oil companies. France’s experience in
            Algeria offered little comfort to the Western industrial nations or Japan. On
            the contrary, it provided them with good reason to treat with extreme caution
            the kind of suggestion thrown out by the shah during the Tehran negotiations
            early in 1971 - that the oil companies should be excluded from the process of

            determining oil prices and production levels, leaving these to be agreed by
            direct arrangement between consuming and producing countries. The shah, of
            course, saw his own role in such government-to-government arrangements as
            that of final arbiter, laying down terms in lofty magisterial fashion. There was
            also a lesson for OPEC, however, in the sour and sullen way in which the
            Franco-Algerian arrangement ended; and this was that sudden and precipitate
            moves towards nationalization as a means of obtaining higher oil revenues
            could produce such unstable conditions in the international oil market that an
   361   362   363   364   365   366   367   368   369   370   371