Page 448 - Arabia the Gulf and the West
P. 448

The ‘Sting*                                          445


        $2,000 million. The loss to Persia, on the basis of her production and revenues

        for lhe same year, would have been about $6,600 million. Obviously, with the
        higher oil prices obtaining in the summer of 1979, the loss of revenue would be
        correspondingly greater, perhaps by as much as 50 per cent. While the richer
        oil states might be able to bear the strain, the less wealthy and more populous
        could not. Nor would the richer states’ clients (notably Syria, Jordan and the

        various Palestinian organizations) forgo their accustomed subsidies with good
        grace.
           That the Arab members of OPEC would have to resort to such extremes to

        secure the acquiescence of the West in any price rise is, however, highly
        unlikely. The inevitability of continual price rises is now accepted by the West
        with much the same fatalism as that with which an Australian aborigine, at
        whom the bone has been pointed, accepts the certainty of impending death.
        Indeed, most public commentators on the subject go further and take a

        perverse pleasure in enumerating the economic tribulations which are about to
        be visited upon the sinful and self-indulgent West by the avenging angel of
        OPEC. Two comparatively recent examples of these attempts at self-fulfilling
        prophecies of doom may suffice to illustrate the kind of thing to be found in

        most leading newspapers and journals of opinion in Europe and North
        America in any week of the year.
           An article in The Times on 16 June 1978 - graced, naturally, with a large
        photograph of Shaikh Yamani - gloomily speculated about forthcoming oil­

        price rises, on the basis of predictions in the oil industry of a 6-10 per cent
        increase in world consumption of oil at the outset of 1979, and of a 15-20 per
        cent increase in the 1980s. That the former figure would equal and the latter
        greatly exceed the average annual rate of increase in the boom years up to 1973

        was not mentioned by the writer. Nor did he attempt to reconcile the predic­
        tions with the existence of a surplus of heavy crudes on the market over the
        preceding eighteen months. Instead, he chose to wax indignant on behalf of the
        OPEC producers over the persistence of this surplus. ‘The oil states, in short,
        are tired of carrying the brunt of the oil glut, fed up of being treated as free

        storage warehouses by Western consumers.’ What, one might ask in some
        'wonderment, had become of the arguments about oil in the ground being the
          est,investment open to the oil states? What of the moral virtues of ‘conserva-

        Uon . To this, the writer had an answer of sorts. ‘Conservation of reserves’, he
        hi ?rmed.his readers ‘. . . inevitably means higher prices. As OPEC sees it,
          *8 er prices will both help to conserve reserves and encourage the develop­
        ment of alternative energy sources.’ In confirmation of this agreeable prospect,

        of °n t0 qU0te from r^e annual report of OAPEC for 1978 on the question
        b er world consumption in the 1980s. ‘Production and price policies must
        lives would create the necessary economic incentives to extend the
        r„S ° Present reserves and increase investments for creating new
        ^serves.
   443   444   445   446   447   448   449   450   451   452   453