Page 10 - The Economist Asia January 2018
P. 10

The Economist January 27th 2018
            10 Leaders
             2 The soft power of patient and consistent diplomacy is vital,  vate. MrTrump and his successors need to redouble the effort.
              but must be backed by the hard power that China and Russia  The best guarantor ofworld peace is a strong America. For-
              respect. America retains plenty ofthat hard power, but it is fast  tunately, it still enjoys advantages. It has rich and capable al-
              losingthe edge in militarytechnologythatinspired confidence  lies, still by far the world’s most powerful armed forces, unri-
              in its allies and fearin its foes.                 valled war-fightingexperience, the bestsystemsengineers and
                To match itsdiplomacy, America needsto investin new sys-  the world’s leading tech firms. Yet those advantages could all
              tems based on robotics, artificial intelligence, big data and di-  too easily be squandered. Without America’s commitment to
              rected-energy weapons. Belatedly, Mr Obama realised that  the international orderand the hard powerto defend it against
              America required a concerted effort to regain its technological  determined and able challengers, the dangers will grow. If
              lead, yet there is no guarantee that it will be the first to inno-  they do, the future ofwarcould be closerthan you think. 7


              Mandatory arbitration in America
              Shut out by the small print




              Millions ofAmerican employees have no recourse to the courts
                                       N 2016 Misty Ashworth sued  firms do have a code of conduct, but less scrupulous firms are
                Mandatory arbitration  Iher employer, Five Guys, a  not policed at all. Studies suggest that repeat business is corre-
                United States, use in non-unionised
                private-sector workplaces  fast-food chain, for sexual ha-  lated with outcomes that favourthe employer.
                                     rassment and constructive dis-  The scales appear to be tilting even further towards bosses.
                1992  2%
                                     missal. But the judge ruled that  Mandatory-arbitration clauses are increasingly paired with
                                     her case could not be heard in  bans on class-action suits by groups of employees. That raises
                2017  54%            court. When she started the job,  the bar for workers to pursue complaints, by ensuring that
                                     she had agreed to take any dis-  each must establish—and finance—his or her case separately; it
              putes with heremployerto private arbitration.      also lowers the risk that misconduct will damage an employ-
                Ms Ashworth is not alone. Across private-sector work-  er’s finances or reputation. The Supreme Court is deliberating
              places in America, non-unionised employees are bound by  whether that violates labour rights. If past form is a guide, the
              mandatory-arbitration agreements. In the early 1990s such  courtwill rule thatitdoesnot: judgeshave consistently treated
              agreements covered only 2% ofnon-unionised workplaces; to-  mandatory arbitration as just anothercontract.
              day they covermore than half.
                The growing use of arbitration is partly an indictment of  Howto increase the font size
              America’s courts. Rarely is it in either side’s interests to litigate  Given that, and the failure of past attempts by Congress to im-
              foryears and at great expense. Arbitration, by contrast, is quick  pose bans, mandatory arbitration seems likely to stay. And in-
              and flexible. It lets both sides choose procedural hoops they  deed, it does have a part to play. Employers should be broadly
              would forgo in return for a speedy resolution. A neutral third  free to contract privately with their workers. A default, low-
              party then hears the evidence and makes a decision.   cost forum for resolving disputes is a good idea—as long as it is
                Arbitration works well when power is balanced between  designed to achieve fair outcomes. Fortunately, decent em-
              the two sides: in commercial disputes between big firms, say.  ployers, ethical arbitrators and sensible regulation can deal
              But the balance between an employer and an employee, par-  with many ofthe problems that bedevil arbitration.
              ticularly in low-wage occupations, is often anything but even  For a start, firms should aim to set up a fair process, by seek-
              (see page 57). And whereas the judicial system is designed, at  ing informed consent, rather than  smuggling arbitration
              least in theory, to treat people equally before the law, manda-  clauses into unrelated documentation. A narrower interpreta-
              tory arbitration puts employees at a furtherdisadvantage.  tion from the courts on what constitutes consent would help,
                Arbitration clauses are often hidden in the contractual  as would an opt-out period foremployees. The clauses should
              small print. Simply acknowledging the receipt of a staff hand-  allow workers to join togetherand to act collectively.
              bookcan count as a binding agreement to the terms it sets out.  Arbitrators should be required to disclose conflicts of inter-
              Even if workers do read everything, almost nobody starts a  est, including whether they have repeat work from the em-
              newjob expectingto have to seekredressagainsttheir employ-  ployer. Options to avoid implicit bias might include manda-
              er. When a dispute goes in front of arbitrators, their decisions  tory rotation of arbitration firms or a system of randomised
              are not subject to a review and, except in rare cases, cannot be  selection. A requirement for arbitrators to offer a written justi-
              appealed against. No public records of arbitration are kept.  fication of their decision would encourage rigorous thinking.
              Even if a worker wins the case, confidentiality provisions can  If arbitrators get the law wrong, employees should be able to
              shield repeatoffendersfrom exposure—asthe ongoingwave of  seekjudicial review.
              workplace-harassment revelations has shown.           Tougher disclosure requirements ought to apply to judg-
                This lack of scrutiny matters, because the incentives of  mentsreached againstthe firm. Employerswould be less toler-
              those who adjudicate disputes are skewed in favour of em-  antofbad behaviouriftheywere required to disclose to inves-
              ployers. Arbitrators are extremely unlikely to come across the  torshowmanysettlementstheyreached and iftheycontinued
              same employee in future cases, whereas repeat business with  to employ repeat offenders. Make such changes, and both em-
              the employer is likely. Such a set-up could strain the neutrality  ployees and employers could benefit from arbitration without
              ofeven the most upstanding arbitrator. Some large arbitration  anyone sacrificingtheirright to a fairhearing. 7
   5   6   7   8   9   10   11   12   13   14   15