Page 16 - The Economist USA
P. 16
UPLOADED BY "What's News" vk.com/wsnws TELEGRAM: t.me/whatsnws
16 Briefing Covid-19 and public finances The Economist April 25th 2020
2 years at an interest rate of just 0.6%. In low- An alternative critique is that the past spoken to Jerome Powell, chairman of the
growth, lower-inflation Japan ten-year may not offer the reassurance some might Federal Reserve, more than 30 times. The
bonds are pegged at around 0%. Only in in- seek there. A preliminary working paper by Bank of England has co-ordinated interest-
debted countries in the euro zone, such as Paolo Mauro and Jing Zhou of the imf, riff- rate cuts with Britain’s treasury and recent-
Italy, do bond yields threaten to exceed re- ing on Mr Blanchard’s theme, examines ly agreed to increase the government’s
cent nominal growth rates. borrowing costs and economic growth for overdraft. The Bank of Japan has long been
These low interest rates make the fiscal 55 advanced and emerging economies over, an enthusiastic partner in the economic
picture seem less bleak. Vitor Gaspar, a se- in some cases, as much as 200 years. agenda of Abe Shinzo, the prime minister.
nior official at the imf, says the fund ex- The 24 advanced economies they study The outlier is the euro zone where, because
pects a combination of low rates and re- have on average benefited from interest of the horror of inflation found in coun-
bounding growth to see debt burdens rates which are below the nominal growth tries such as Germany and the Nether-
stabilise or decline in the “vast majority” of rate 61% of the time. Yet they find that such lands, political pressure on the ecb is just
countries in 2021. And bond-buying by differentials are “essentially useless” for as likely to result in hawkish policy.
central banks takes much of the worry out predicting sovereign defaults. “Can we
of some of the debt. sleep more soundly” with interest rates be- Facing the exigencies
Take Japan. Its gross-debt-to-gdp ratio low growth rates? they ask. “Not really,” Conveniently for politicians, some of the
in 2019 was around 240% of gdp, which they answer. pain of high inflation would be borne by
sounds truly astonishing. But years of The first sign of any debt trouble in the foreign investors, whose share of public
quantitative easing (qe) have left the Bank rich world would probably be rising infla- debt exceeds 30% in many rich countries.
of Japan with government bonds worth tion. At first, that might be a relief, given “In a crunch, will Chinese debt-holders be
nearly 85% of gdp. And the government the present deflationary risk and the recent treated as senior to us pensioners?” asks
could, in theory, sell financial assets of a history of persistently insufficient infla- Mr Rogoff. But less foreign investment in
similar magnitude if it had to. Adjust the tion. It would be a sign that the economy years to come would need to be set against
debt to take these things into account and that advantage. A perception that a nomi-
what remains is a little over 70% of gdp— nally independent central bank was in fact
less than a third of the gross figure and a creature of politicians would create a risk
roughly comparable to what the figure is premium on investment that would slow
for America if you make the same adjust- growth throughout the economy.
ments (see chart 2 on previous page). Inflation would bring arbitrary redistri-
Well before the pandemic such analysis butions of wealth to the disadvantage of
had led many influential economists to the poor, just as Keynes observed it to have
start treating higher public debt as sustain- done in the late 1910s. Richer people are
able in a low-inflation, low-interest-rate more likely to hold the houses and shares
world. Because the pandemic has pushed that rise in value with inflation, not to
both inflation and interest rates the same mention mortgages that would be inflated
way—down—their logic still holds. How- away alongside government debt. Higher
ever, there are reasons for scepticism. inflation would also provide a bail-out that
Start with central-bank debt holdings. favoured more indebted companies over
qe does not really neutralise public debt. the less indebted.
Central banks buy government bonds by Higher taxes, tried a little in the wake of
creating new money which sits in the the financial crisis, could be targeted more
banking system in the form of reserves. precisely to reduce inequality—much as
And central banks pay interest on those re- they were in some countries after the sec-
serves. Because the central bank is ulti- ond world war. Wealth taxes, as favoured
mately owned by the government, qe re- was recovering. By reducing real interest by Keynes back then and increasingly dis-
places one government debt-interest bill, rates it would further boost growth. And cussed by academics and left-wing politi-
interest payments on bonds, with another, central banks that have long fallen a per- cians today, could find that their time had
interest payment on bank reserves. And al- centage point or so short of their inflation come. Post-pandemic populations may
though the latter are very low today—nega- targets might feel comfortable seeing infla- welcome the sort of cost-free-to-most all-
tive, in fact, in several places—they will tion ride a percentage point or so proud of in-it-togetherness they might provide.
stay so only so long as central banks do not it. But a somewhat relaxed attitude to 3% Less radically, a value-added tax in America
need to raise rates to fight inflation. does not mean a willingness to accept 6%. (which lacks one), higher taxes on land or
Since the global financial crisis, betting Inflation rising further above targets inheritance, or new taxes on carbon emis-
on low rates has paid off; some have gone than it has been below them would bring sions could be on the cards. Like inflation,
so far as to see them as a new normal, part on a stark choice for heavily indebted gov- however, tax rises inhibit and distort the
of a low-growth economy in which de- ernments. Should they leave the central economy while producing a backlash
mand needs constant stimulation. But that bank alone, let it raise rates to keep infla- among those who must pay.
brings out another flaw in the sanguine tion at target, and look to taxpayers—or While the world’s chief problem is bat-
view of public debt: it assumes that the fu- pensioners—to pay for the resulting rise in tling an economic slump in which infla-
ture will be like the past. Although markets debt-interest costs? Or should they lean on tion is falling, such choices are tomorrow’s
expect rates to remain low, it is not a sure their central banks to keep interest rates business. They will not weigh heavily on
thing. There is, for example, the possibility low, permitting inflation to rise and there- policymakers’ minds. Even economists
that lockdowns and stimulus in close suc- by easing their debt burdens? with reputations as fiscal hawks tend to
cession do indeed bring on price rises. Some context for that question comes support today’s emergency spending, and
There is also the possibility that a great deal from the blurring between fiscal and mon- some want it enlarged. Yet one way or an-
of the deflationary pressure has been due etary policy the pandemic has already other, the bills will eventually come due.
to oil prices, which as of today really do seen. Steve Mnuchin, America’s treasury When they do, there may not be a painless
seem to have no further to fall. secretary, has said that on some days he has way of settling them. 7