Page 613 - Microeconomics, Fourth Edition
P. 613

c14gametheoryandstrategicbehavior.qxd  8/6/10  8:22 AM  Page 587







                                                       14.2 THE REPEATED PRISONERS’ DILEMMA                     587

                      APPLICA TION  14.4
                      Shoot-to-Kill, Live-and-Let-Live,                are better off when both “live-and-let-live” than when

                      or Tit-for-Tat?  15                              both “shoot-to-kill.” The structure of the “game” be-
                                                                       tween opposing battalions along the Western front
                                                                       was thus a prisoners’ dilemma.
                      Trench warfare is ugly and brutal. This was certainly  But if “shoot-to-kill” was a battalion’s dominant
                      so along the Western front during World War I, where  strategy, why did cooperation emerge? The reason,
                      the Allied army (France and Britain) faced the German  Axelrod argues, is that the prisoners’ dilemma game
                      army. Still, as Robert Axelrod has written, despite the  between enemy battalions was a repeated game.
                      grim circumstances, an unusual degree of coopera-  Trench warfare differs from other ways of fighting a
                      tion emerged. Axelrod quotes a British staff officer  war because each side’s units face the same enemy
                      who wrote that he was:                           units for months at a time. Although cooperation be-
                                                                       tween Allied and German battalions usually evolved
                         astonished to observe German soldiers walking  by accident (e.g., during periods of unusually rainy
                         about within rifle range behind their own line. Our
                         men appeared to take no notice. I privately made  weather during which fighting could not occur), the
                         up my mind to do away with that sort of thing  close interaction between the same battalions allowed
                         when we took over; such things should not be   them to follow strategies that tended to sustain the
                         allowed. These people evidently did not know  cooperation once it had emerged.
                         there was a war on. Both sides apparently believed  A particularly valuable strategy for sustaining
                         in the policy of “live and let live.”         cooperation between enemy battalions along the
                                                                       Western front was “tit-for-tat.” Under this strategy,
                      Axelrod goes on to point out that these circumstances
                                                                       you do to your opponent what your opponent did to
                      were not isolated. “The live-and-let live system,” he
                                                                       you last period. Along the Western front, it became
                      writes, “was endemic in trench warfare. It flourished
                                                                       well understood that if one side exercised restraint,
                      despite the best efforts of senior officers to stop it,
                                                                       the other would, too. If, by contrast, one side fired,
                      despite the passions aroused by combat, despite the
                                                                       the other side would shoot back in a proportional
                      military logic of kill or be killed, and despite the ease
                                                                       fashion. Wrote one soldier:
                      with which the high command was able to repress
                      any local efforts to arrange a direct truce.”       It would be child’s play to shell the road behind
                         Axelrod interprets the “cooperative” trench war-  the enemy’s trenches, crowded as it must be with
                      fare along the Western front as the outcome of a    ration wagons and water carts, into a bloodstained
                      repeated prisoners’ dilemma game. At any given point  wilderness . . . but on the whole there is silence.
                                                                          After all, if you prevent your enemy from drawing
                      along the line, the two players were Allied and German
                                                                          his rations, his remedy is simple: he will prevent
                      battalions (military units consisting of roughly 1,000
                                                                          you from drawing yours.
                      men). On any given day, a battalion could “shoot-to-
                      kill,” a strategy corresponding to “cheat” in Table 14.12.  The “tit-for-tat” strategy was carried to strong numer-
                      Or it could “Live-and-Let-Live,” a strategy that corre-  ical extremes. One soldier noted:
                      sponds to “cooperate” in Table 14.12. Axelrod
                                                                          If the British shelled the Germans, the Germans
                      argues that for each opposing battalion “shoot-to-kill”
                                                                          replied, and the damage was equal: if the Germans
                      was a dominant strategy. This is because each battalion
                                                                          bombed an advanced piece of trench and killed
                      would occasionally be ordered by its army’s high com-  five Englishmen, an answering fusillade killed five
                      mand into a major battle in its area of the line (e.g., a  Germans.
                      charge against the other side’s trenches). By shooting
                      to kill, a battalion would weaken its opponent, which  The use of tit-for-tat strategies meant that each
                      would increase the likelihood of survival should a major  side realized that an aggressive act would be met by
                      engagement be ordered. At the same time, both sides  an aggressive response. In choosing how to fight,


                      15 This example draws heavily from Chapter 4 of Robert Axelrod’s book, The Evolution of Cooperation
                      (New York: Basic Books, 1984), pp. 73–87.
   608   609   610   611   612   613   614   615   616   617   618