Page 548 - Krugmans Economics for AP Text Book_Neat
P. 548

The area of the shaded rectangle is:

                                                Area = Height × Width = $40 per room × 5,000 rooms = $200,000,

                                       or

                                                           Tax revenue = Area of shaded rectangle

                                          This is a general principle: The revenue collected by an excise tax is equal to the area of a rec-
                                       tangle with the height of the tax wedge between the supply price and the demand price and the width
                                       of the quantity sold under the tax.


                                       The Costs of Taxation
                                       What is the cost of a tax? You might be inclined to answer that it is the amount of
                                       money taxpayers pay to the government—the tax revenue collected. But suppose the
                                       government uses the tax revenue to provide services that taxpayers want. Or suppose
                                       that the government simply hands the tax revenue back to taxpayers. Would we say in
                                       those cases that the tax didn’t actually cost anything?
                                          No—because a tax, like a quota, prevents mutually beneficial transactions from oc-
                                       curring. Consider Figure 50.10 once more. Here, with a $40 tax on hotel rooms, guests
                                       pay $100 per room but hotel owners receive only $60 per room. Because of the wedge
                                       created by the tax, we know that some transactions didn’t occur that would have oc-
                                       curred without the tax. More specifically, we know from the supply and demand curves
                                       that there are some potential guests who would be willing to pay up to $90 per night
                                       and some hotel owners who would be willing to supply rooms if they received at least
                                       $70 per night. If these two sets of people were allowed to trade with each other without
                                       the tax, they would engage in mutually beneficial transactions—hotel rooms would be
                                       rented. But such deals would be illegal because the $40 tax would not be paid. In our
                                       example, 5,000 potential hotel room rentals that would have occurred in the absence of
                                       the tax, to the mutual benefit of guests and hotel owners, do not take place because of
                                       the tax.
                                          So an excise tax imposes costs over and above the tax revenue collected in the form of
                                       inefficiency, which occurs because the tax discourages mutually beneficial transactions.
                                       You may recall from Module 9 that the cost to society of this kind of inefficiency—the
                                       value of the forgone mutually beneficial transactions—is called the deadweight loss.
                                       While all real-world taxes impose some deadweight loss, a badly designed tax imposes a
                                       larger deadweight loss than a well-designed one.
                                          To measure the deadweight loss from a tax, we turn to the concepts of producer and
                                       consumer surplus. Figure 50.11 shows the effects of an excise tax on consumer
                                       and producer surplus. In the absence of the tax, the equilibrium is at E and the equilib-
                                       rium price and quantity are P E and Q E , respectively. An excise tax drives a wedge equal to
                                       the amount of the tax between the price received by producers and the price paid by con-
                                       sumers, reducing the quantity sold. In this case, with a tax of T dollars per unit, the quan-
                                       tity sold falls to Q T . The price paid by consumers rises to P C , the demand price of the
                                       reduced quantity, Q T , and the price received by producers falls to P P , the supply price of
                                       that quantity. The difference between these prices, P C − P P , is equal to the excise tax, T.
                                          Using the concepts of producer and consumer surplus, we can show exactly how
                                       much surplus producers and consumers lose as a result of the tax. We learned previ-
                                       ously that a fall in the price of a good generates a gain in consumer surplus that is
                                       equal to the sum of the areas of a rectangle and a triangle. Similarly, a price increase
                                       causes a loss to consumers that is represented by the sum of the areas of a rectangle and
                                       a triangle. So it’s not surprising that in the case of an excise tax, the rise in the price
        The deadweight loss (from a tax) is the  paid by consumers causes a loss equal to the sum of the areas of a rectangle and a trian-
        decrease in total surplus resulting from the  gle: the dark blue rectangle labeled A and the area of the light blue triangle labeled B in
        tax, minus the tax revenues generated.  Figure 50.11.
        506   section 9     Behind the Demand Curve: Consumer Choice
   543   544   545   546   547   548   549   550   551   552   553