Page 120 - Microeconomics, Fourth Edition
P. 120

c03consumerpreferencesandtheconceptofutility.qxd  6/14/10  2:54 PM  Page 94







                  94                    CHAPTER 3   CONSUMER PREFERENCES AND THE CONCEPT OF UTILITY





                                                                                               U , the utility from
                                                                   3                            3
                                                                                               three pairs of shoes
                                                                 L, Left shoes  2  G  H        U , the utility from
                                                                                                2
                                                                                               two pairs of shoes
                    FIGURE 3.14   Indifference Curves with Perfect                             U , the utility from
                                                                                                1
                    Complements                                    1                           one pair of shoes
                    The consumer wants exactly one left shoe for every
                    right shoe. For example, his utility at basket G, with
                    2 left shoes and 2 right shoes, is not increased by  0  1  2     3
                    moving to basket H, containing 2 left shoes and 3        R, Right shoes
                    right shoes.


                                           The consumer with the preferences illustrated in Figure 3.14 regards left shoes
                  perfect complements   and right shoes as perfect complements in consumption. Perfect complements are
                  (in consumption) Two  goods the consumer always wants in fixed proportion to each other; in this case, the
                  goods that the consumer  desired proportion of left shoes to right shoes is 1:1. 11
                  always wants to consume  A utility function for perfect complements—in this case, left shoes (L) and right
                  in fixed proportion to each  shoes (R)—is U(R, L)   10min(R, L), where the notation “min” means “take the min-
                  other.
                                        imum value of the two numbers in parentheses.” For example, at basket G, R   2 and
                                        L   2; so the minimum of R and L is 2, and U   10(2)   20. At basket H, R   3 and
                                        L   2; so the minimum of R and L is still 2, and U   10(2)   20. This shows that bas-
                                        kets G and H are on the same indifference curve, U 2 (where U 2   20).

                                        THE COBB–DOUGLAS UTILITY FUNCTION

                  Cobb–Douglas utility  The utility functions U   1xy  and U   xy are examples of the Cobb–Douglas utility
                  function A function of  function. For two goods, the Cobb–Douglas utility function is more generally repre-

                  the form U   Ax y ,   sented as U   Ax y , where A,  , and   are positive constants. 12

                  where U measures the con-  The Cobb–Douglas utility function has three properties that make it of interest
                  sumer’s utility from x units
                  of one good and y units of  in the study of consumer choice.
                  another good and where
                  A,  , and   are positive  • The marginal utilities are positive for both goods. The marginal utilities are
                  constants.               MU x    Ax  	1                    	1 ; thus, both MU x and MU y are positive
                                                         y and MU y    Ax y
                                           when A,  , and   are positive constants. This means that “the more is better”
                                           assumption is satisfied.
                                         • Since the marginal utilities are both positive, the indifference curves will be
                                           downward sloping.
                                         • The Cobb–Douglas utility function also exhibits a diminishing marginal rate
                                           of substitution. The indifference curves will therefore be bowed in toward the
                                        11 The fixed-proportions utility function is sometimes called a Leontief utility function, after the economist
                                        Wassily Leontief, who employed fixed-proportion production functions to model relationships between
                                        sectors in a national economy. We shall examine Leontief production functions in Chapter 6.
                                        12 This type of function is named for Charles Cobb, a mathematician at Amherst College, and Paul
                                        Douglas, a professor of economics at the University of Chicago (and later a U.S. senator from Illinois).
                                        It has often been used to characterize production functions, as we shall see in Chapter 6 when we study
                                        the theory of production. The Cobb–Douglas utility function can easily be extended to cover more than

                                        two goods. For example, with three goods the utility function might be represented as U Ax y z ,
                                        where z measures the quantity of the third commodity, and A,  ,  , and   are all positive constants.
   115   116   117   118   119   120   121   122   123   124   125