Page 571 - Microeconomics, Fourth Edition
P. 571

c13marketstructureandcompetition.qxd  7/30/10  10:44 AM  Page 545







                                                13.2 OLIGOPOLY WITH HOMOGENEOUS PRODUCTS                        545
                         Now let’s consider what Samsung will do. If it understands that LG acts as a
                      profit-maximizer, it will recognize that LG will choose its output according to its
                                        . This means that by its choice of output, Q , Samsung can, in
                      reaction function R LG                                  1
                      effect, place the industry somewhere along its rival’s reaction function. For example,
                      we can see from Figure 13.6 that if Samsung chose Q   15, then LG would choose
                                                                   1
                      an output of 37.5 units and the industry would end up at point A. If, by contrast,
                      Samsung chose Q   60, then LG would choose an output of 15 and the industry
                                     1
                      would end up at point F.
                         Which output should Samsung choose? It should choose the output that maxi-
                      mizes its profits. To illustrate where this profit-maximizing quantity is located, the
                      table in the upper right-hand corner of Figure 13.6 shows the market price and
                      Samsung’s profit at a variety of points along LG’s reaction function. For example, at
                      point A (where Samsung produces 15 units and LG’s best response is to produce 37.5
                      units) the market price is 100   15   37.5   $47.5 per unit, and Samsung’s profit
                      equals ($47.5   $10)   15   $562.50. Of the points shown, the quantity of output
                      that gives Samsung the highest profit is at point S, at which Samsung produces 45
                      units of output, which in turn induces LG to produce 22.5 units of output.
                         We can verify this with some calculations. Recall that the market demand curve
                      is given by the equation P   100   Q   Q . But since Q is chosen so that Q
                                                       1
                                                                         2
                                                            2
                                                                                           2
                      $45    Q /2, it follows that the market price will ultimately depend on Samsung’s
                              1
                      quantity choice: P   100   Q   (45   Q /2), or P   55   Q /2. This expression can
                                                         1
                                               1
                                                                          1
                      be thought of as the residual demand curve faced by the Stackelberg leader in that it
                      tells the leader how the market price will vary as a function of its quantity choice,
                      taking into account the follower’s reaction to that quantity choice.
                         Finding Samsung’s optimal quantity choice is now straightforward. We identify
                      the marginal revenue curve corresponding to the leader’s residual demand curve, and
                      find the quantity that equates this marginal revenue to the leader’s marginal cost. The
                      associated marginal revenue curve is MR   55   Q , and equating this marginal rev-
                                                                 1
                      enue to Samsung’s marginal cost yields
                                              55   Q   10, or Q   45
                                                     1
                                                               1
                      In response to this choice of output by the leader, the follower chooses output level
                      Q   45   45/2   22.5.
                       2
                         Notice that the Stackelberg equilibrium outcome (point  S) differs from the
                      Cournot equilibrium outcome (point C). Unlike the Cournot outcome, which was
                      symmetric, under the Stackelberg outcome, the leader produces more output than the
                      follower (exactly twice as much in fact). In fact, even though the market price is lower
                      under the Stackelberg outcome than under the Cournot outcome (compare the mar-
                      ket price at point S to that at point C in Figure 13.6), the leader’s profit under the
                      Stackelberg outcome is higher than its profit at the Cournot equilibrium. This tells us
                      that an oligopolist benefits by choosing its output first. Where does this benefit come
                      from? Essentially, by choosing its output first, the leader, Samsung, can “manipulate”
                      LG’s output choice to its advantage. In particular, when Samsung chooses a quantity
                      that is greater than its Cournot equilibrium quantity, it forces LG into a position in
                      which LG’s optimal response is to choose a quantity that is less than its Cournot equi-
                      librium quantity. (We can see this from the fact that LG’s reaction function is downward
                      sloping.) The intuition for why LG is forced into this position can be seen by imagining
                      how LG’s managers might react when they learn about Samsung’s decision to produce
                      the relatively large quantity of output at point S.
   566   567   568   569   570   571   572   573   574   575   576