Page 576 - Microeconomics, Fourth Edition
P. 576

c13marketstructureandcompetition.qxd  7/30/10  10:44 AM  Page 550







                  550                   CHAPTER 13   MARKET STRUCTURE AND COMPETITION

                  APPLICA TION  13.3
                  U.S. Steel: The Price of Dominance        22
                                                                   TABLE 13.6   U.S. Steel’s Market Share,
                                                                   1901–1935
                  With sales of over $6 billion, the U.S. Steel group of
                  the USX Corporation is one of America’s largest steel          Market             Market
                  companies. But while large in absolute terms, U.S.     Year     Share     Year     Share
                  Steel currently accounts for less than 15 percent of   1901      66%      1920     46%
                  U.S. domestic steel sales. At one time, though, U.S.   1905      60%      1925     42%
                  Steel was much more dominant. In fact, when it was     1910      54%      1930     41%
                  formed (by merger) in 1901, U.S. Steel produced 66     1915      51%      1935     33%
                  percent of the steel ingot sold in the United States. In
                  those days, U.S. Steel was a classic dominant firm.
                      However, as Table 13.6 shows, U.S. Steel’s market                             23
                                                                   those of its rivals, actual or potential.”  In addition,
                  share soon began to decline, and by the mid-1930s, it
                                                                   as Scherer notes, entry into the steel industry in the
                  had fallen to 33 percent of the market. According to
                                                                   early twentieth century took time. It required build-
                  economic historians Thomas K. McCraw and Forest
                                                                   ing an integrated steel mill, and in those days it was
                  Reinhardt:
                                                                   not easy to secure either financial capital or reliable
                                                                   sources of iron ore.
                      For three decades [1900–1930], U.S. Steel followed  As a result, it probably made sense for U.S. Steel
                      patterns of pricing and investment that guaran-
                      teed an erosion of its market share. Instead of  to eschew an aggressive limit pricing strategy and
                      raising barriers to entry into the steel industry,   instead set prices at or close to the levels implied by
                      it lowered them. It neither tried vigorously to   the dominant firm model. And as we saw from Figure
                      retain its existing markets nor to take advantage  13.8, with an expanding fringe, this implied an ero-
                      of new growth opportunities in structural and  sion of the dominant firm’s share over time. Hideki
                      rolled markets (p. 616).                     Yamawaki provides some statistical evidence that U.S.
                                                                   Steel actually behaved this way. 24  Using data on steel
                      Why didn’t U.S. Steel follow an aggressive strat-  prices and production (by U.S. Steel and rival firms)
                  egy of limit pricing to slow the expansion by rival  from that era, Yamawaki shows that U.S. Steel’s pric-
                  firms? Our discussion of dominant firm pricing sheds  ing decisions were influenced by the market share of
                  light on this question. Scholars who have studied the  fringe producers. He also shows that the price set by
                  history of U.S. Steel believe that before World War II  U.S. Steel significantly influenced the fringe’s rate of
                  (1941–1945), U.S. Steel probably did not have an ap-  production and the rate at which the fringe expanded
                  preciable cost advantage over its competitors. F. M.  over time. Based on this evidence, we can conclude
                  Scherer writes, “Although some of the Corporation’s  that the logic of the dominant firm model nicely fits
                  plants may have had lower costs, on average USS  competitive dynamics in the U.S. steel industry from
                  could pour and shape steel at costs no lower than  1900 to 1940.







                                        22 This example was inspired by a fuller and more detailed discussion of U.S. Steel’s history and dominant
                                        firm pricing behavior by F. M. Scherer in Chapter 5 of his book Industry Structure, Strategy, and Public
                                        Policy (New York: HarperCollins, 1996). The quotation below and the data in Table 13.6 come from
                                        T. K. McCraw and F. Reinhardt, “Losing to Win: U.S. Steel’s Pricing, Investment Decisions, and Market
                                        Share, 1901–1938,” Journal of Economic History 49 (September 1989): 593–619.
                                        23 F. M. Scherer, Industry Structure, Strategy, and Public Policy (New York: HarperCollins, 1996), p. 155.
                                        24 H. Yamawaki, “Dominant Firm Pricing and Fringe Expansion: The Case of the U.S. Iron and Steel
                                        Industry, 1907–1930,” Review of Economics and Statistics 67 (August 1985): 429–437.
   571   572   573   574   575   576   577   578   579   580   581