Page 664 - Microeconomics, Fourth Edition
P. 664

c15riskandinformation.qxd  8/16/10  11:10 AM  Page 638







                  638                   CHAPTER 15   RISK AND INFORMATION
                                        rival drops out when you raise the bid to $801. As a result, you are able to buy a table
                                        that is worth $1,000 to you for a price of $801.

                                        Second-Price Sealed-Bid Auctions
                                        Now suppose that the seller uses a second-price sealed bid auction to sell the antique
                                        table. What bid should you submit? This auction seems much more complicated than
                                        the English auction or the first-price sealed-bid auction. Interestingly, though, game
                                        theory again yields a clear statement of ideal bidding behavior: Each bidder’s domi-
                                        nant strategy is to submit a bid equal to the bidder’s maximum willingness to pay. That
                                        is, if your valuation of the table is $1,000, then submitting a bid of $1,000 is at least as
                                        good as—and sometimes better than—submitting, any other bid, no matter what bids
                                        you think rival bidders will submit. To see why, consider your options:

                                         • If you bid less than your maximum willingness to pay of $1,000, you might win
                                           or you might not, depending on the valuation of the other player. But no matter
                                           what, you cannot hurt yourself by increasing your bid to $1,000 because, if you
                                           win, you don’t pay your own bid but instead pay a price equal to the second-
                                           highest bid. And by increasing your bid you might even help your chances of
                                           winning. Thus, any bid less than your maximum willingness to pay is dominated
                                           by a bid exactly equal to your maximum willingness to pay.
                                         • What about bidding more than your maximum willingness to pay of $1,000, say
                                           $1,050? This might seem appealing because you don’t actually pay your bid.
                                           The problem is that this strategy can never help you, and it can sometimes hurt
                                           you. If your rival bids more than $1,050, raising your bid from $1,000 to $1,050
                                           doesn’t help you; you will lose the auction either way. If your rival bids less
                                           $1,000, you would have won anyway if you had kept your bid at $1,000, and so
                                           again, raising your bid doesn’t help you. And if the rival bids between $1,000
                                           and $1,050, you win the table, but you’ve paid a price that is more than it is
                                           worth to you. You would have been better off bidding $1,000 and not winning
                                           the table. Thus, any bid that is greater than your maximum willingness to pay is
                                           never better and sometimes worse than a bid that is exactly equal to your maximum
                                           willingness to pay.

                                           If each bidder follows the dominant strategy and submits a bid equal to the
                                        bidder’s maximum willingness to pay, you will submit a bid equal to $1,000, while your
                                        rival (whose valuation we have assumed to equal $800) will submit a bid of $800. As
                                        in the English auction, you win the item, and the price that you pay—$800—is virtu-
                                        ally identical to the $801 that you would have paid in an English auction. Remarkably,
                                        the second-price sealed-bid auction, even though it entails different rules than the
                                        English auction, generates virtually the same result. (The difference arises because in
                                        the English auction we restricted the bid increment to $1. In general, the difference
                                        between the payment made by the winning bidder in an English auction and a second-
                                        price-sealed-bid auction depends entirely on the size of the bidding increment. If, in
                                        the theoretical extreme, the bidding increment were vanishingly small, the payments
                                        in the two auction formats would be equal.)


                                        Revenue Equivalence
                                        We have seen that under the three auction formats we have considered (first-price
                                        sealed-bid auction, English auction, and second-price sealed-bid auction), when
   659   660   661   662   663   664   665   666   667   668   669