Page 665 - Microeconomics, Fourth Edition
P. 665

c15riskandinformation.qxd  8/16/10  11:10 AM  Page 639







                                                                                15.5 AUCTIONS                   639
                      bidders have private values and each bidder follows the Nash equilibrium strategy, the
                      bidder with the highest willingness to pay wins the auction. We have also seen that:

                       • In a first-price sealed-bid auction, the winning bidder pays a price that is less
                         than his or her maximum willingness to pay.
                       • In an English auction and in a second-price sealed-bid auction, the winning
                         bidder pays a price that is equal to the second-highest private valuation among
                         all the bidders in the auction.

                      Thus, each format successfully identifies the bidder with the highest valuation, but the
                      seller’s revenue (the winning bid) is less than that highest valuation. Remarkably, the
                      seller’s revenue in English and second-price sealed-bid auctions—the second-highest
                      private valuation among all the bidders in the auction—is also the seller’s revenue in
                      first-price sealed-bid auctions and in all other types of auctions when bidders have private
                      values and follow Nash equilibrium strategies. This surprising result (which is too com-
                      plex to derive here) is called the revenue equivalence theorem: When bidders have  revenue equivalence
                      private values, all auction formats generate the same revenue for the seller, equal on  theorem  When partici-
                      average to the second-highest private valuation among all the bidders in the auction.  pants in an auction have
                                                                                                private values, any auction
                                                                                                format will, on average,
                      AUCTIONS WHEN BIDDERS HAVE COMMON VALUES:                                 generate the same revenue
                      THE WINNER’S CURSE                                                        for the seller.
                      When bidders have common values, a complication arises that does not occur when
                      bidders have private values, the winner’s curse: The winning bidder might bid an  winner’s curse  A
                      amount that exceeds the item’s intrinsic value. To see how this can happen, suppose  phenomenon whereby
                      your economics professor brings a briefcase full of dollar bills to class and auctions it  the winning bidder in a
                      off. Every student is given a peek inside the briefcase to estimate how much it con-  common-values auction
                      tains. You estimate that it contains $150, which represents the most you would be will-  might bid an amount
                                                                                                that exceeds the item’s
                      ing to bid. Of course, your classmates develop their own estimates, and these might  intrinsic value.
                      differ from yours. Let’s suppose that these estimates are distributed according to the
                      dashed bell-shaped curve shown in Figure 15.15. The height of this curve indicates






                          Frequency of estimates and bids  Distribution of bids  Distribution of estimates  FIGURE 15.15  The Winner’s Curse

                                                                                   in an Auction with Common Values
                                                                                   The dashed bell-shaped curve shows the
                                                                                   distribution of bidders’ estimates, cen-
                                                                                   tered on the item’s intrinsic value of
                                                                                   $80. The solid bell-shaped curve shows
                                                                                   the distribution of bids, assuming that
                                                                                   bidders shade their bids as they would
                                                                                   in an auction with private values. The
                                                                                   winning bid will be in the right-hand
                                                                                   half of the distribution of bids and
                                                                                   might be in the shaded region, where
                                                         80  100   150             bids are greater than the item’s intrinsic
                                                                                   value. If so, the winning bidder will
                                            Estimates and bids in dollars
                                                                                   have suffered the winner’s curse.
   660   661   662   663   664   665   666   667   668   669   670