Page 482 - Microeconomics, Fourth Edition
P. 482

c11monopolyandmonopsony.qxd  7/14/10  7:58 PM  Page 456







                  456                   CHAPTER 11   MONOPOLY AND MONOPSONY

                  By contrast, retailers believe that baby food and dis-  demand for baby food and disposable diapers. If so,
                  posable diapers are not purchased impulsively. They  the IEPR implies that we should see precisely what
                  believe that most consumers of these products put  we do see: higher markups for chewing gum and
                  considerable thought into their purchase decisions  candy than for baby food and disposable diapers.
                  and pay close attention to price when deciding how  For these products, at least, grocery stores seem to
                  much to buy. This suggests that the demand for   set retail prices in a manner that is broadly consistent
                  chewing gum and candy is less price elastic than the  with the IEPR.




                                        down, your profit goes up. Thus, at any point on the inelastic region of the market
                                        demand curve, the monopolist can always find a point on the elastic region that gives
                                        it a higher profit.
                                           We can use the IEPR to reach the same conclusion. To see why, we start with the
                                        (perhaps obvious) observation that marginal cost is positive. This implies that the
                                        term 1   (1/  Q,P )  in equation (11.3) must also be positive. But the only way this term
                                        can be positive is if   Q,P  is between  1 and  q, that is, if demand is price elastic.
                                        Thus, the IEPR implies that the monopolist’s profit-maximizing price and quantity
                                        occur along the elastic region of the market demand curve.




                                        THE IEPR APPLIES NOT ONLY TO MONOPOLISTS
                                        The IEPR applies to any firm that faces a downward-sloping demand for its product,
                                        not just to monopolists. Consider, for example, the pricing problem Coca-Cola faces.
                                        Coca-Cola does not have a monopoly in the U.S. cola market: Pepsi is an important
                                        competitor. Still, Coca-Cola and Pepsi are not perfectly competitive firms. In other
                                        words, if Coca-Cola raised its price, it would not lose all its sales to Pepsi, and if it
                                        lowered its price, it would not steal all of Pepsi’s business. The reason for this is that
                  product differentiation  the two colas exhibit  product differentiation, a condition in which two or more
                  A situation in which two or  products possess attributes that, in the minds of consumers, set the products apart
                  more products possess   from one another and make them less than perfect substitutes. Some people prefer the
                  attributes that, in the minds  sweeter taste of Pepsi to the less sweet taste of Coke and would continue to buy Pepsi
                  of consumers, set the prod-  even if it cost more than Coke. You might prefer the taste of Coke. Or you might be
                  ucts apart from one another
                  and make them less than  indifferent about the taste but prefer Coca-Cola’s packaging or advertisements.
                  perfect substitutes.     Differentiated products will have downward-sloping demand curves, even though
                                        the sellers of the products are not monopolists. The optimal pricing decision for a
                                        seller of a differentiated product can thus be characterized by a rule very much like
                                        the IEPR. For example, the optimal price markups for Coca-Cola and Pepsi (denoted
                                        by A and I, respectively) would be described by

                                                                   A
                                                                  P   MC   A      1
                                                                       A
                                                                      P
                                                                                 Q A, P A
                                                                     I
                                                                   P   MC  I      1

                                                                       P I         Q I , P I
                                        In these formulas,            are not market-level price elasticities of demand.
                                                         Q A , P A  and   Q I ,P I
                                        Rather, they are the brand-level price elasticities of demand for Coca-Cola and Pepsi.
   477   478   479   480   481   482   483   484   485   486   487